Do asset transfer programmes lead to child labour? Evidence from Philippines

Article

Published 20.11.20
Photo credit:
© ILO/Joseph Fortin

Asset transfers can expand household-based economic activity, but can also draw more children into the labour force when other labour is unavailable

One-time productive asset transfers to poor families are a fundamental piece of the anti-poverty toolkit. Such transfers, whether delivered in relative isolation or bundled in a package of services as in the BRAC’s Ultra-poor Graduation Programs (Banerjee et al. 2015), lead to growth in household-based economic activity.  

Where does the labour to work in these new economic activities come from? We identify 58 impact evaluations of one-time productive asset transfer programmes, of which 31 report results related to the impact of the asset transfer on employment. While a handful report negligible effects on employment, most document increases in household-based economic activity. For instance, Bandiera et al.’s (2017) study of a graduation programme in Bangladesh shows that when livestock is transferred to ultra-poor households, the treatment leads women to work more and devote more time to livestock rearing. In the 31 evaluations with employment information, beneficiaries shift household labour from existing activities towards the new household-based economic activity, instead of hiring additional labour.

If households have surplus labour, the labour demands associated with new productive assets might be easily accommodated, but few ultra-poor households have such surplus.  Sometimes, the need for labour to work the new asset diverts labour out of less productive activities (de Hoop et al. 2020). However, because of asymmetric power structures within households, agency problems are endemic in their labour supply decisions. Children and other vulnerable family members thus might be more likely to bear the burden of rising household labour demands. 

In our study (Edmonds and Theoharides 2020), we examine who works after a productive asset transfer to families with child labour in the Philippines. Such transfers are a central part of the anti-child labour toolkit. There is ample evidence on the income elasticity of child labour supply, and asset transfers have the potential to permanently push households to a level of wealth where they are capable of sustaining and growing their income, eliminating motives for child labour. The obvious concern is that these anti-child labour projects may increase child labour by drawing children into work because of the new productive asset.

The programme

A central piece of the Philippine government’s efforts against child labour is a programme for households with child labourers called Kabuhayan Para sa Magulang ng Batang Manggagawa (KASAMA). The programme, implemented by The Philippine Department of Labor and Employment (DOLE), is designed to promote sustainable forms of income that replace families’ use of child labour. Our study is a clustered randomised control trial (RCT) of KASAMA conducted in partnership with DOLE and in advance of an intended national expansion of the programme.

KASAMA provides in-kind transfers worth 10,000 Philippine pesos (PHP) (US$518 purchasing power parity) in an asset of the beneficiary’s choice, including equipment, tools, and/or raw materials for production. The most common assets transferred are for the creation or expansion of small convenience (‘sari-sari’) stores. 

The evaluation

The study is located in five regions on the Philippine island of Luzon. Two of these regions, Bicol and Central Luzon, account for more than 20% of all child labourers in the Philippines (ILO 2011). Seventy four percent of the children in the families in our study are engaged in child labour, most commonly in agriculture, retail, and domestic work. 

To measure the impact of the programme, we randomly assign 164 communities (barangays) to either a treatment group which is offered KASAMA, or a control group which is not. Each group includes 82 communities, with 14 households in each community (1,148 households in each group).

The evaluation began in February 2016, and households started receiving assets in August 2016. We measure impacts of the programme approximately 18 months after the assets were distributed to capture any changes that may have persisted beyond the initial distribution. Our data collection primarily consists of quantitative household surveys, with an emphasis on household income-generating activities and time allocation. 

A unique aspect of our study is that we directly interview all adolescents (aged 10 to 17) both prior to the intervention and 18 months after asset distribution. Of the 58 impact evaluations that we reference above, only four examine child time allocation and none interview children directly. Our interviews with adolescents allow us to collect detailed self-reported measures of time allocation and to directly measure socio-emotional well-being.

Findings

Treatment expands household-based income generating activity  

The number of family firms increases among both control and treatment groups from the baseline to the end-line. Three-quarters of control households report a family firm at end-line, and treatment households are 10 percentage points more likely to report a family firm at end-line (see Figure 1). Family firms include both agricultural and non-agricultural activities. Our results translate into 476 enterprises created and an additional 120 expanded among the 1,148 treatment households.  

Figure 1 Growth in family firms in treatment group

Existing child labourers do not stop working, but other children start working when they are the available labour   

The treatment does not impact the overall economic activity rate of children. This aggregate finding masks growth in economic activity by children who were not engaged in labour at baseline. For this subsample, we find an eight percentage point (12%) growth in economic activity and no apparent improvement in child wellbeing (see Figure 2). These children start working because they are part of the available labour. The median age of household members who are not economically active at baseline is 15.

Figure 2 Treatment effects on children by baseline child labour status

Labour is especially scarce in households with enterprises at baseline. With treatment, more of their children enter the labour force 

For households with an enterprise at the baseline, there are fewer economically inactive members, and those inactive members are younger, with a median age of 14 (see Figure 3). For such households with limited available labour, treatment further burdens children, drawing them into potentially hazardous (and obviously illegal) work conditions. The 45% increase in hazardous child labour is driven by worsening working conditions. 

Figure 3 Treatment effects on child employment by baseline enterprise status (limited to children not engaged in labour at baseline)

Did an anti-child labour programme increase child labour?

The Philippine government’s asset transfer programme for families of child labourers grows economic activities in beneficiary households and as a result, on net, children report being better off. However, it does not limit child labour, and the growth in demand for labour in households leads to more children becoming economically active. Despite a growth in household income, these new child labourers do not report improvements in their wellbeing.  

While this programme is targeted at households with existing child labour, it raises concerns that are relevant to a larger set of programmes. Asset transfers, graduation programs, and microfinance schemes all aim to grow household-based economic activity, and this study highlights that there should be questions about where the labour for such new activity comes from. 

The lack of attention to issues around children’s labour supply is most striking in Save the Children’s (2019) guidance brief for how to conduct “Child Sensitive Graduation Programming Design”. While the brief lists “engaged in harmful work” as a child deprivation that should be considered for targeting graduation programmes, there is no attention paid to the possibility that children could be pulled into work by the programme. 

Evidence from the Philippines underscores the importance of considering how children are impacted by asset transfers. Understanding this may require directly interviewing children to weigh the benefits of the programme for the household against the new set of stressors imposed on children.

References

Bandiera, O, R Burgess, N Das, S Gulesci, I Rasul, and M Sulaiman. 2017. “Labor markets and poverty in village economies”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 132(2): 811-870.

Banerjee, A, E Duo, N Goldberg, D Karlan, R Osei, W Pariente, J Shapiro, B Thuysbaert, and C Udry (2015), “A multifaceted program causes lasting progress for the very poor: Evidence from six countries”, Science 348(6236): 1260799.

de Hoop, J, V Groppo and S Handa, on behalf of the Malawi Social Cash Transfer Program and the Zambia Multiple Category Targeted Program study teams (2020), “Cash Transfers, Microentrepreneurial Activity, and Child Work: Evidence from Malawi and Zambia”, The World Bank Economic Review 34(3): 670–697.

Edmonds, E and C Theoharides (2020), “The Short Term Impacts of a Productive Asset Transfer in Families with Child Labor: Experimental Evidence from the Philippines”, Journal of Development Economics 146.

International Labor Organization (2011), 2011 Survey on Children 5 to 17 Years Old, Final Report.

Save the Children (2019), “Child Sensitive Graduation Programming Design”.